Let's start with an often invoked motivation for impact minimization efforts I find logically uncompelling: pending catastrophic environmental outcomes stemming directly from resource shortages. While well-informed, cogent versions of this argument, e.g., this, this or this, are definitely worth considering, I still find them partially persuasive at best, offering a weak model of reality. But what I mostly argue against below is less nuanced, resource scarcity literalism (see, e.g., this).
The reason that argument
has not often carried the day—and I doubt it will very
often in the future—is innovation; when availability of a given
resource declines appreciably, but well before it becomes materially
scarce, market motivated research and technical innovation are focused
on improving methods of locating and extracting the resource, or in
some cases into identifying abundant alternatives for hard to get
resources, restoring the availability-to-demand ratio of the original
resource. For example, consider
this
brilliant example of obviating the need for hard to get, polluting,
heavy metals with, well, dirt. Or take natural gas and oil proven
global reserves (shown in Figure 1 for 1980-2007); have these reserves
declined in recent decades?! Not really, despite rapidly rising
cumulative consumption. (But it is true that the rate of
supply increase has now leveled off, and will begin declining in the
not too distant future.) How is that possible?! Improved extraction
technologies (for example, the deep ocean—now a major fossil
energy source, as this paragraph's upper right figure makes clear,
made popularly infamous by the
Deepwater Horizon explosion—was all but closed for oil
exploration until a couple of decades ago).
Is this behavior unique? some inexplicable, irreproducible fluke of fossil fuels? No, not really. Take, for instance, global reserves of the three industrially important metals figure 2 addresses. Over roughly four decades starting in the mid-'50s, the ratios of those reserves and their respective global demands have not really changed appreciably, and at times have actually gone up. Figure 2 does not have the telltale appearance of a pending scarcity catastrophe, even though during this time actual cumulative demand of these metals increased dramatically. Clearly, the rate at which we discover new deposits of these metals has roughly kept pace with rising demands.
Are there limitations to this view? Are some resources hitting the immovable wall of resource finality applies? To some extent there are. Take, e.g., the aspects of global agricultural production figure 3 summarizes, portraying a mixed, nuanced picture. Over the shown roughly half century, world arable land as a percent of global land area has expanded steadily, at least through 1990 (figure 3a), but only by about 10% at most. At the same time, world population (b) has more than doubled. As a result of the arable land expansion falling well short of population growth, per capita arable land area (c) declined by 45% (the 2009 value is 55% of 1961's). At the same period, however, per acre productivity of cereals and other crops (3d) has gone way up. We can derive an overall crop production index per capita, by dividing panel 3d's green curve, per acre crop productivity, by population, 3b's blue curve. This scaled index (3e)—arguably the most pertinent measure of food supply adequacy, at least in terms of average food quantity—has increased by more than 40% between 1961 and 2009.
While the significant growth in per capita crop production over the last half century is consistent with my contention that hitting the wall of actual material scarcity is rarely realized, the decline in per capita arable land is not. The apparent self-contradictory duality of the food production example showcases the current food system's main triumph, seemingly inexorably rising supply of food calories, while also implicitly emphasizing (as I demonstrate below) its equally important shortcoming, the large and rising environmental costs the supply increases have exacted. This dualism also highlights what I view as the key failing of the "hitting the scarcity wall" argument:
To appreciate the dilemma, consider the environmental costs the expanding caloric supply has exacted. While this expansion is partially attributable to agricultural land expansion (figure 3a, and see also further down), its central element is rising per acre productivity (figure 3d). In turn, the two key ingredients of rising per acre productivity are irrigation and fertilizer, both with major environmental consequences. Let's examine irrigation withdrawals first. While figure 4a shows a factor of 5 or so rise in Irrigation water withdrawal (IWW, blue), arguably more remarkable is the close tracking of global total and irrigation related consumptive withdrawals (Gwc and IWC, respectively, essentially the net water losses). What this close tracking means is that the lion's share of the rise in global water consumption is attributable to irrigation, which is of course consistent with the (logistic-like) rise in both crop- and pasturelands figure 4b shows. Note that consumptive water use comprises all water uses that directly compete with (and sometimes rob) other uses. For example, consumptive use for irrigation in California's central Valley directly competes with, and undermines, ecological integrity of Western aquatic ecosystems and species. This often amounts to a simple zero-sum choice between agriculture and other uses, such as, e.g., the choice between the water needs of farmers, Native Americans, and wild salmon in Oregon's Klamath Basin or the Columbia. So it is not running out of water—a geophysical virtual impossibility on large scales—we should be concerned with, but the rising environmental costs of exploiting ever more oversubscribed existing supplies.
Another aspect of the expanding irrigation fueling the steadily rising per acre productivity is the need for dams. When irrigation is the deciding factor (figure 4c's green dots), the dams are needed in order to regulate major river flows so as to maximize water extraction capacity when withdrawal (i.e, in many cases, primarily irrigation) needs dictate, not when the rivers naturally crest. Dams, a dominant continental scale global presence (figure 4c), raise many serious environmental issues. This is too broad a topic to address here in any meaningful way (you can read a nice review of dam hydrology here and a discussion of the benefits, as well as a few short-term pitfalls, of dam removal here), but suffice is to say that globally proliferating dams and the reservoirs upstream of them (figure 4d shows a roughly 12-fold increase in global storage capacity upstream of dams) are a key force behind human alteration of landscapes, the hydrological cycle on land, biodiversity declines, and species endangerment, among many other undesirable impacts. Again, it is not running out rivers to dam that is most concerning, but the environmental burdens existing and planned dams exert.
The second element of agriculture's rising per acre output is fertilization. In this issue too, the scope of the problem and the volume of literature documenting nitrogen fertilizer's many adverse environmental impacts far exceed the scope of this modest venue (this, this or this are nice lay-person introductions, while a classic scientific introduction is here). Below I therefore summarize briefly a few key issues. Here again, the point is that the main issue with food supply is not so much running out of land—we can easily double the number of adequately but not overly nourished people globally over a year or two timescale with significant but tractable structural changes to the food production system—but the rising environmental costs of getting more out of existing agricultural land while failing to reconsider priorities, customs, preferences and resource allocation patterns. Graphically, the problem is the logistic nature of many resource extraction histories, such as those shown in figure 4a, b or d: a rapidly (quasi-exponentially, if you want to get technical) rising phase (e.g., 1930-1975 in figure 4a or 1950-1975 in figure 4d), followed by declining rates (during which the curves gradually level off, approaching horizontal lines, e.g., after 1985 in figure 4d). This leveling off indicates that we still need more, but manage to add less and less as time goes on; that's precisely the time for innovation to kick in, to displace demand toward more available resources.
A life saver in some circumstances and a driving force behind the
Green Revolution (see this
or this),
overuse of nitrogen fertilization comes at staggering environmental
costs. To begin with, its production uses tremendous amounts of fossil
fuels (both for energy and as a raw material, the latter alone
accounting for 4% of global natural gas consumption),
contributing about 1.2% to global greenhouse gas emissions, and to
air
pollution. The trick here is that the source of all N used for
fertilizer is the atmosphere, which is almost 80% N. But nitrogen in
the atmosphere is in the form of molecular nitrogen, N
By far most troublesome is nitrogen fertilizer's central role in
undermining water quality in rivers, ponds and lakes, and the world
coastal oceans. In a nutshell, the issue is as
follows. Nutrients—elements, primarily nitrogen and phosphorus,
needed for basic life functions such as protein synthesis; think about
nutrients as "food" plants need—in most natural, undisturbed
aquatic systems (e.g., pristine ponds or lakes) are fully or nearly
used up by plants (algae), so that the nutrient concentrations in the
upper water column are nearly zero. Then, the system
"productivity"—how much carbon in the form of atmospheric
CO2 the system transforms, or fixes, into living tissue per
unit time—is maximized, and any further productivity enhancement
is limited by nutrient availability. If additional nutrients are
somehow introduced into the system—by fertilizer rich runoff in
most cases—nutrient availability limitations on productivity are
at least temporarily removed, and productivity rises. Think about
wading into a warm pond in August through a thick, green slimy mat of
aquatic vegetation, and you get the picture, or you can go
here
for breath taking photos. These events are called algal "blooms", and
you can see an example below (figure 5).
In coastal oceans and estuaries the world over
(see this
compelling map of global distribution), algal blooms occur, on a grand
scale, typically in summer. Some (e.g., in the cold coastal waters
along northern California, Oregon and Washington) are perfectly
natural. Many, however, are due to fertilizer rich runoff from
agricultural intensive lands (the one in the northern Gulf of Mexico
off the
mouth of the Mississippi is particularly notorious and
well-documented). Figure 6 presents some aspect of dead zone mechanism
and fishery consequences.
And marine life forms? Well, they need dissolved oxygen, without which
they suffocate. Large fishes in small, mild hypoxic regions can swim
away. Shellfish and other slow- or non-moving creatures of the sea, on
the other hand, die, just like the crab figure 6 depicts,
posthumously. Figure 6's lower left inset shows the history of effort
required for Gulf of Mexico shrimping; clearly the bottom area that
needs to be scoured for a fixed shrimp catch increases with passing
years, with every decade's average catch per ha lower than the
previous decade's average.
I hope the above synopsis' brevity doesn't obscure the scope,
magnitude and seriousness of reactive nitrogen (biologically available
nitrogen not locked in the largely inert N2 molecule)
impacts on aquatic environments. Given the severity of the problem,
the high environmental costs of fertilization, you probably envision a
global trend underway toward ever increasing fertilization efficiency,
toward getting more out of less. As figure 7 makes clear, just the
reverse is true, with decreasing yields per unit N applied in all
continental agroecological systems. For example, in the U.S., grain
mass produced per N mass applied declined from roughly 90 in 1960 to
about 30 in recent years. Further, the longer a continental
agroecological system has been subject to routine, widespread
fertilization, the less responsive its yield is too added nitrogen,
with western Europe getting the least grain, followed by the U.S.,
culminated by South America, whose industrial fertilization history
is, on average, much shorter. Here again, the issue is not so much
running out of land to feed the world, but rather the ostentatiously
wasteful way we go about using available land.
As I mentioned earlier, a less impactful, yet very
environmentally costly, element of rising agricultural productivity
(figure 3e) is expanded agricultural land. While figure 3a quantifies
the process globally, figure 8a breaks it down regionally. In the
developed world (e.g., North America here; Europe—not
shown—behaves similarly until 1990, but features a massive jump
following the collapse of the Soviet Union), agricultural lands have
either held steady or declined slightly. Conversely, in the developing
world (e.g., figure 8a's uppermost three curves), agricultural land
extent steadily rises. The important issue here again is the
environmental costs of this rise, mostly through tropical
deforestation.
If you are a
Hubbert
Peak (HP) aficionado, you may appreciate the following HP-inspired
interpretation of my point. Just to get everybody on the same page,
let's review briefly some necessary HP background.
Suppose you are interested in a given resource, whose cumulative
production rate pc is given by figure 10's equation
1, where pmax gives the total amount of the resource
known or thought to exist. Note that while at any given
time pmax is thought to be a given constant,
technological advances may require updating its value
periodically. The larger α is, the smaller the initial
cumulative production rate as a fraction of pmax is,
and the larger β is, the faster the resource is exhausted.
The rate at which the resource is produced at any given time—the
instantaneous production rate—is the time derivative
of pc(t), p(t), given by figure 10's equation
2. Figure 10a shows pc(t) for pmax
= [100, 130, 160, 190, 220], with α = 80 and β = 0.02 in
all 5 cases, in red, green blue, cyan and magenta,
respectively. Similarly, figure 10b shows pc(t) for
the same 5 cases.
The real world relevance of this is that equation 1, and thus figure
10a's curves, describe very well availability of most resources on
which humans depend. When a resource first becomes crucially relevant
to humans (e.g., coal immediately following Watt's introduction of the
steam engine, or oil shortly after cars became widely available),
its exploitation or extraction rises rapidly (exponentially), e.g.,
between t = 40 and t = 180 in figure 10a. After a while,
however, most of the low hanging fruits have been picked, so that
continued extraction or exploitation comes at an increasingly rising
cost (e.g., while the first oil wells were only vertical and tapped
land reservoirs just beneath the surface, today's reservoirs can be
some 10 km beneath the bottom of a 3 km deep ocean, and can comprise
equally long horizontal segments).
Now consider the hypothetical scenario in which the instantaneous
production is 0.5 (the horizontal black line in figure 10b). Imagine
this instantaneous production rate is first achieved when your best
estimate of the total resource available is pmax =
100 (shown in red). From an overall availability standpoint, this
instantaneous production rate is realized where figure 10a's black
curve intersects that panel's red curve. (For ease of visualization,
figure 10c reproduces a magnified version of figure 10a's gray shaded
region.) Next, suppose technological innovation pushes your best
estimate of total resource availability to pmax =
130 (shown in green). Following the same logic, from an overall
availability standpoint, this instantaneous production rate is now
(after pmax was updated from 100 to 130) realized
where figure 10a's black curve intersects that panel's green curve;
clearly earlier relative to total availability. Follow the same
argument until pmax = 220 (magenta), traversing
figure 10c along the black curve from upper right to lower
left. Because as pmax increases along [100,220]
(corresponding graphically to the
red→green→blue→cyan→magenta progression) the black
curve's crossing of the cumulative production curves occurs earlier
relative to total availability, the percent exhausted at that point
gets smaller, as figure 10d makes clear.
With the HP perspective, innovation is the force moving cumulative
production curves to the left, thereby yielding earlier relative times
at which a given instantaneous production rate is realized, and thus
smaller corresponding exhaustion percent. This is why the resource
scarcity argument is, in my view, a weak one.
Several coupled key reasons.
1. Financial
savings: This is an obvious one; most optimization
measures save money, and some save lots of money.
2. Duty: Today,
most traditional resources and some emergent ones (e.g., various
precious metals needed for modern IT) are at the declining phase of
their availability, like figure 10a's curves after, say, t =
280. They are not yet scarce in any simple meaning of the word, but
they sure are getting more environmentally expensive to extract and
exploit. At that point, when resource additions are slow and
declining, availability becomes almost a zero-sum game, with use by
one person meaning reduced availability to others, so that continued
unchecked resource use by one directly undermines the well being of
others. This to me is arguably the most compelling reason to minimize
impact. At this point, it is very tempting to invoke no lesser
authority than
Immanuel
Kant, whose moral duty idea, especially his first
formulation of the categorical imperative, is extremely pertinent:
3. Elegance: Think
of, e.g., Lance Armstrong's biking, Marlon Brando's acting, Fred
Astaire's dancing, or Hemingway's writing. As I see it, what sets them
apart, what makes them great, is economy. Having studied their
disparate crafts to perfection, they eliminated all that's not
essential, and nothing more, until they were left with the irreducible
essence of their crafts. Perfection, that's easily identifiable even
for those not particularly interested in the specific craft.
This observation also applies to most any human-environment
interaction. Virtually any resource use can be made more economic,
parsimonious, efficient; virtually anything we do involving resource
use can be achieved with less, sometime dramatically less. If it
is possible to build a financially tractable, attractive house whose
operation requires no fossil fuels, and that even over its full life
cycle (including construction and manufacturing of all elements) uses
dramatically less fossil fuels (e.g.,
this
or
this
claim to—and might—do just that), why wouldn't you?! If
you can get from a to b
by car using a fraction of the gas, why wouldn't you?!
4. The health
connection: This addresses personal benefits, in departure
from the benevolence of the first and the abstraction of the
second. Much of modern resource use replaces the use of human muscles;
driving instead of walking, elevator riding instead of climbing
stairs, leaf blowing instead of raking, to name but a few random
examples. Yet the human body has evolved for muscle work; the evidence
documenting its rapid functional degradation and declining quality of
life is overwhelming. There is thus a direct parallel in many aspects
of resource use: the less you use, the healthier you are.
The coastal ocean
typically comprises, in a highly idealized manner, two layers
(right). In the top layer (spanning the surface to a depth, highly
variable in space and time, ranging from a few, to tens, or even
hundreds or more meters below the surface), sea water is typically
fairly warm and fresh, and thus light. Below the top layer is a
thicker layer containing heavier, colder, often saltier water . Figure
6's schematic shows these two layers, separated by the thick cyan
line, the so-called pycnocline (a thin layer, marked "rapid
transition" in the upper right figure, in which water density
increases rapidly with depth, idealized here as a single
line). Because this configuration is stable (lighter water rides over
denser water), the two stacked water masses exchange heat and other
properties sluggishly (vertical mixing is slow). Near the surface,
where in summer water is intensely heated by the sun and is thus
warmer and more buoyant, there is plenty of sunlight for algal
photosynthesis. Algal growth is thus so ubiquitous, using up nearly
all the nutrients in the surrounding water. The importance of the
pycnocline is that it prevents replenishing upper layer nutrients by
deeper, nutrient rich water, because raising the lower layer's heavier
water required energy. Thus under normal conditions, algae growth near
the ocean surface is limited by nutrient availability. But if you add a
strong flux of nutrient rich water from a river draining a large
agricultural province (e.g., the Mississippi), the upper left thick
arrow into the figure 6's "ocean", you lift this limitation. The
result is an algal bloom near the surface, shown as the greenish upper
layer. There, the water is very rich with oxygen both because of the
proximity to the atmosphere and because of internally produced
O2 due to the algal photosynthesis. The blooming algae live
briefly, and die quickly. Some of this dead organic matter makes its
way to the bottom, where it behaves just like that head of lettuce
forgotten in the back of your refrigerator; it decomposes, or
decays. Organic matter decomposition—the reverse of
photosynthesis—requires rather than generates oxygen. The needed
O2 is supplied by the water column, and the result is
O2 depleted water column. The oversubscribed oxygen
supplies of the near bottom waters could have been replenished by
downward oxygen flux from surface waters that are oxygen saturated
because of their intimate contact with the overlaying atmosphere, but
this flux is rendered too sluggish by the afore-mentioned
stratification—near surface waters less dense, or more buoyant,
than deeper, denser, waters—to suffice. This is hypoxia (low
dissolved oxygen) or, if it's even more intense, anoxia; either means
insufficient levels of dissolved oxygen in the water.
Last modified on
GMT by Gidon Eshel